Quarterly Outlook
Fixed Income Outlook: Bonds Hit Reset. A New Equilibrium Emerges
Althea Spinozzi
Head of Fixed Income Strategy
Chief China Strategist
"You know my method. It is founded upon the observation of trifles."
- Sherlock Holmes in Conan Doyle (1891) The Boscombe Valley Mystery
As China's leadership prepares for the long-awaited Third Plenary Session of the 20th Central Committee, announced on April 30 to be held in July, a consultative meeting on May 23 with private entrepreneurs and economists, chaired by General Secretary Xi Jinping, has stirred speculation that the top leadership might be preparing the country for a shift towards more pro-market reforms.
In recent years, communications from the Chinese leadership have predominantly emphasized the state sector and industrial policies. These industrial policies are state actions meant to allocate resources in support of selected industries to achieve goals determined by political processes with significant political stakes. While the focus on industrial policies will continue to be the core pillar of China’s development strategies, the inclusion of economics professor Zhou Qiren as one of the nine selected speakers at the consultative meeting suggests that the top leadership might make use of his market-oriented views and the symbol he carries to send a signal.
Zhou contends that the drastic fall in transaction costs, organization costs, and most importantly system costs was the primary driver of China's astonishing growth rate in the three decades since its reform and opening started in 1978. He claims that system-wide institutional reforms are crucial for the Chinese economy to regain cost advantages and achieve breakthroughs, rather than relying on aggregate demand stimulus and industrial policies.
While we caution against putting too much weight on Zhou himself or academia in general regarding the Chinese leadership’s deliberation on economic development models, the signalling implication is hard to ignore. Zhou has been absent from the spotlight for quite some time and is well known for his alternative views on the driving forces of the Chinese economy. His new institutional economics roots, which were first popularized by Ronald Coase, emphasize the central roles of institutional arrangements in the economy, property rights, transaction costs, and political economy in economic development. This approach is markedly different from the New Keynesian approach that dominates the mainstream economic profession or the Marxist political economy that the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) maintains as the overarching guiding principle in economic thought.
Furthermore, Xi rarely chairs consultative sessions with private entrepreneurs himself. Over the past decade, besides this recent one, the previous consultative session with the private sector chaired by Xi was in July 2020 during the COVID-19 pandemic, and the one before that was in November 2018 when China and the US were embroiled in a trade war. This time, Xi held the meeting right before the Third Plenary Session, which will formulate the long-term strategic direction and development model of China. The selection of Zhou as a speaker at this meeting carries significant symbolism and could serve to send out signals. What Zhou said at the meeting is not as important as what Zhou is perceived to represent.
According to Zhou, China's economic miracle is not a result of low-cost labour but a consequence of system-wide institutional reform and the opening up of the economy that lowered the ‘system costs’ of China’s economy. Zhou (2017) defines ‘system costs’ as the costs incurred in the operation of the institutional framework of enforcing property rights and contracts. The essence of China’s reform is to “redefine property rights by decentralizing the power of the super state-firm” (Zhou, 2010). The narrative that China's economic success is solely due to cheap labour is overly simplistic. Before the economic reforms, China's labour was even cheaper, but the country did not experience the same economic boom. Today, many countries around the world also offer cheaper labour, yet they do not replicate China's success. This discrepancy underscores that low labour costs alone are insufficient for economic transformation.
As Zhou(2023) points out, the critical factor is the transformation of these inputs into more products that are competitive. This requires effective organization and functioning within a supportive institutional framework to lower transaction costs, organization costs, and most importantly system costs. Before reforms, China's highly centralized economic system, akin to a "super state-firm," was plagued by inefficiencies and high organizational costs. By decentralizing economic control and redefining property rights, China significantly lowered these costs, thereby enhancing its competitiveness. China's initial reforms, such as the shift from collective farming to a household farm production contractual responsibility system, followed by allowing the establishment of private enterprises to absorb the labour freed from farm activities, exemplify the impact of institutional change. These reforms not only increased agricultural productivity but also released labour for the growing industrial sector, creating a foundation for China's manufacturing boom. Moreover, China's opening to and engagement with global markets, highlighted by its economic and regulatory reforms which earned its accession to the WTO, illustrate the importance of institutional support in leveraging low-cost labour.
The problem China is now facing, according to Zhou (2023), is that system costs in China have been rising fast due to dramatic increases in costs incurred by higher taxes and charges, local governments pushing up land prices, and more regulations, as well as inconsistencies in dealing with new technologies in the private sector and the inefficiency of state-driven urbanization. These changes have stifled economic progress. His prescription for the Chinese economy is to lower system costs through reform and opening the economy and to innovate. Reducing system costs through streamlined regulations, greater transparency, and better definition and enforcement of property rights is essential for fostering growth and innovation.
In our article published in October 2023, we asked if the upcoming Third Plenary Session could mark a pivotal moment for China's economic strategy, potentially embracing pro-market reforms and emphasizing the market's "decisive role" in allocating resources, as outlined in a blueprint unveiled by the Chinese leadership 10 years ago. The “Decision of the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China on Some Major Issues Concerning Comprehensively Deepening the Reform,” adopted at the Third Plenary Session of the 18th Central Committee held in November 2013, pledged to deepen marketization and privatization. However, these initiatives have petered out over the years. The May 23 meeting, as discussed above, gives a glimmer of anticipation that the upcoming Third Plenary Session this July might echo the 2013 Decision, contrary to the downbeat expectations of investors regarding its outcome.
Once again, we want to emphasize that the Chinese top leaders' adherence to focusing on fostering new productive forces, a concept rooted in the Marxist political economy, and their commitment to state-driven industrial policies to boost self-reliance and comprehensive national security, along with their strategic initiatives in deleveraging the economy and containing the monopoly power of large private enterprises, will remain. What we are exploring is the plausibility that the top leadership is sending signals that they are preparing to fine-tune their strategic development model, at least tactically, to foster the market and the private sector. It is important to remember that the Chinese leadership has demonstrated remarkable pragmatism over the past few decades in steering the gigantic Chinese economy. A tactical change to green in the “traffic light” that regulates the reform of the institutional frameworks in which the economy functions is plausible.
We are not predicting what will happen at the Third Plenary Session in July because Zhou spoke at Xi’s consultative meeting on May 23. We are simply exploring what might have happened that made Zhou’s high-profile appearance at the meeting possible. We hope that thinking through this non-consensus observation as one of the possibilities of what has been going on will better prepare investors to interpret the outcome of the Third Plenary Session when it arrives in July.
2024-05-29 Understanding the Surge in the Japanese Equity Market and Corporate Share Buybacks
2024-05-27 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Challenges and Opportunities in China’s Electric Vehicle Industry
2024-05-21 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: New Approach to Housing Policy and Market Implications
2024-05-13 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Barbell Tactical Trades on High Dividend and Technology Names
2024-03-19 US Election: Shaking Up Chinese Equities and the Renminbi?
2024-03-04 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Decoding Expectations about the Two Sessions
2024-02-06 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: The Stormy Waters of the Chinese Equity Market
2024-01-12 Taiwan's 2024 Elections: Balancing Geopolitical Realities and Economic Pragmatism
2024-01-09 Investing in China: Navigating Q1 amid economic challenges
2023-11-07 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Central Financial Work Conference Unveils Near-Term Bullish Signals
2023-10-12 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Central Huijin Increases Stakes in the Four Largest SOE Banks
2023-10-09 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Evaluating the Potential Rebirth of Pro-Market Reforms
2023-10-05 Understanding the Surge in Bond Yields: Term Premium, not “higher for longer”
2023-10-03 No one's indestructible
2023-09-27 China/Hong Kong Market Pulse: Property Debt Overhang, Recovery Signs, and Policy Outlook
2023-08-21 Macro Update: Ceasing Interest Payments on Reserve Balances in a Fiscal Dominance Regime
2023-08-08 China Update: Investing in China's High-Quality Development Initiatives
2023-07-25 China Updates: Politburo Focuses on Quality Growth and Industry Policies
2023-07-06 China faces challenges from generative AI amidst the fragmentation game
Disclaimer
The Saxo Bank Group entities each provide execution-only service and access to Analysis permitting a person to view and/or use content available on or via the website. This content is not intended to and does not change or expand on the execution-only service. Such access and use are at all times subject to (i) The Terms of Use; (ii) Full Disclaimer; (iii) The Risk Warning; (iv) the Rules of Engagement and (v) Notices applying to Saxo News & Research and/or its content in addition (where relevant) to the terms governing the use of hyperlinks on the website of a member of the Saxo Bank Group by which access to Saxo News & Research is gained. Such content is therefore provided as no more than information. In particular no advice is intended to be provided or to be relied on as provided nor endorsed by any Saxo Bank Group entity; nor is it to be construed as solicitation or an incentive provided to subscribe for or sell or purchase any financial instrument. All trading or investments you make must be pursuant to your own unprompted and informed self-directed decision. As such no Saxo Bank Group entity will have or be liable for any losses that you may sustain as a result of any investment decision made in reliance on information which is available on Saxo News & Research or as a result of the use of the Saxo News & Research. Orders given and trades effected are deemed intended to be given or effected for the account of the customer with the Saxo Bank Group entity operating in the jurisdiction in which the customer resides and/or with whom the customer opened and maintains his/her trading account. Saxo News & Research does not contain (and should not be construed as containing) financial, investment, tax or trading advice or advice of any sort offered, recommended or endorsed by Saxo Bank Group and should not be construed as a record of our trading prices, or as an offer, incentive or solicitation for the subscription, sale or purchase in any financial instrument. To the extent that any content is construed as investment research, you must note and accept that the content was not intended to and has not been prepared in accordance with legal requirements designed to promote the independence of investment research and as such, would be considered as a marketing communication under relevant laws.
Please read our disclaimers:
- Notification on Non-Independent Investment Research (https://www.home.saxo/legal/niird/notification)
- Full disclaimer (https://www.home.saxo/en-gb/legal/disclaimer/saxo-disclaimer)